For next time read Berndt 3.5,3.6.
Todays class.
The game plan

- 1. Model learning curves

- 2. Model production functions

- 3. Model costs associated with production function

- 4. Specialize cost function to include the learning curve model
as a special case
1. Learning curves

- The motivation

- Unit costs decrease as cumulative output increases.

- Strategic implications for pricing and marketing strategy

- Formulation

where
-
is unit cost in time period t (adjusted for inflation) -
is unit cost in initial time period -
cumulative production up to but not including time t -
is unit cost elasticity with respect to cumulative volume -
stochastic disturbance term (our
)

- Note. Response is unit cost. A multiplicative model.

- Make linear by taking logs.


- Estimate
from a simple regression.
2. Cobb Douglas production function.

- Model:
where
- y is the output
- A denotes the state of technical knowledge
-
denotes the quantity of input i -
is the parameter to be estimated (like an elasticity of output with respect to input i)

- Note: the response is output. Another multiplicative model.

- Define returns to scale as
3. The cost function

- The cost function is
.

- Just the quantity of inputs times their prices.

- Relates the minimum cost of producing a level of output y to the
prices of the inputs and the state of technical knowledge.
Objective;
Find the input levels that minimze the production cost for a given
level of output. (Cost minimizer assumption.)
This is an optimization problem, in particular choose input levels to
minimize costs. But subject to a constraint: the inputs must produce a
given level of output, y.
Mathematical technique for solution of constrained optimization:
Lagrange multipliers.
It turns out that, assuming the Cobb Douglas production function, then
the optimal level of inputs produce a COST FUNCTION of the form
where
It looks a mess, but notice that it is multiplicative, so taking logs will
achieve a linear expression ready for regression.
Further, using the fact that
the logged
version can be rewritten as
where
From this lot we can get at what's of interest,
.
4. Putting together the Learning Curve and the Cost Function
Objective: make assumptions that incorporate the learning curve into the
cost function as a special case.
- Recall that the learning curve equation can be written as
- And the cost equation as
Then the question becomes can we put restrictions and assumptions on the
cost function so that the learning curve is a special case?
Here's how it goes.
- Define the state of knowledge
as
. - Assume that effects of the input prices are captured by a GNP deflator,
ie
This leads to a simpler equation:
Here
is a real total cost because it as been adjusted by the GNP
deflator.
Finally move to unit real costs rather than total real costs and you obtain
which for r = 1 is the learning curve model.
How much sense does the previous equation make?
It says that the log of your average real cost at time t depends on
two things.
- 1, how much you have produced up to time t which surrogates for
how much knowledge you have.
- 2, how much you produce at time t as denoted
by
. If you produce more and your returns to scale are greater than 1
(r > 1) then your average cost should decrease - which makes sense.
Summary
We have seen a variety of econometric models in action.
- There were all multiplicative.
- Their functional form was convenient to work with.
- They involved some very strong assumptions.
- Criticism should be tempered by the objective of the modeling.
- They provide a framework and language for discussion rather than a vague conversation.
Richard Waterman
Wed Oct 1 20:47:26 EDT 1997